Since the end of Second World War, the US share in world GDP has fallen from nearly 30 per cent to about 18 per cent.
Other advanced economies have also experienced sustained declines in their respective slices of the global pie. But you wouldn’t know it from looking at the international monetary system.
Over the same period, China’s share of world GDP almost quadrupled, to around 16 per cent (just behind the US), and emerging markets now account for about 60 per cent of global output, up from about 40 per cent in the immediate post-war years. Given that advanced-economies’ growth prospects remain subdued, these trends are likely to continue — even with the evident slowing in China and other emerging markets.
And yet global finance has not mirrored this shift in balance from the advanced to the emerging. The post-war Bretton Woods arrangements institutionalised the role of the US dollar as the main reserve currency, and until the 1970s, about two-thirds of global GDP was anchored to the greenback. The remainder was largely split between the British pound and the Soviet ruble.
In a recent study that I undertook with Ethan Ilzetzki and Kenneth Rogoff, we document that the US dollar has retained its dominant position as the world’s reserve currency — and by a significant margin. Over 60 per cent of all countries (accounting for more than 70 per cent of world GDP) use the US dollar as their anchor currency.
Other metrics, which include the proportion of trade invoiced in dollars and the share of US assets (notably Treasuries) in central banks’ foreign exchange reserves, suggest a similar degree of “dollar dominance”.
The euro is a distant second. From the early 1980s, until the introduction of the euro in 1999, the Deutsche Mark’s (DM) influence expanded first in Western Europe and later in Eastern Europe. But the rise of the euro, which consolidated the DM and French franc (Africa) zones, appears to have stalled.
By some measures (given the shrinking share of Europe in world output), its global importance has declined.
No other major established international currencies currently compete for global leadership. The divergence between the trends for production and finance emerges as a relatively smaller US economy supplies reserve assets in step with rising global demand for them (primarily from emerging markets).
This divergence is not entirely new. With recovery from Second World War underway in Europe and global trade expanding, demand for reserves grew rapidly in the 1950s and remained high into the early 1970s. At that time, the US dollar was backed by gold.
Given that the world’s gold supplies were not increasing as fast as global demand for reserves, the gap was filled by US (paper) debt.
Over time, fulfilling the global demand for reserves caused a steady rise in the ratio of “paper dollar” reserves to gold reserves, which was incompatible with maintaining the official dollar/gold parity. The incompatibility of the national goal (maintaining the parity) and America’s international role as sole provider of the reserve currency was the essence of the dilemma that the Belgian economist Robert Triffin foresaw (as early as 1960) as a risk to the Bretton Woods system.
Two devaluations, relative to gold, in December 1971 and February 1973, were not enough to correct the “overvaluation” of the US dollar. The Bretton Woods system came to an end in March 1973, when the dollar and other major currencies were allowed to float and the dollar depreciated further.
Now as then, the US could meet the rest of the world’s appetite for dollars by issuing more dollar debt. This would require the US to run sustained current-account deficits, mirrored in fiscal deficits.
Of course, while the link to gold is passe, any domestic fiscal objective to curb US debt growth would be at odds with the international role as sole provider of the reserve currency.
One way or another, China will figure prominently in the resolution of this modern “Triffin dilemma”. One possibility is that the inevitable reduction of US current-account deficits (whenever that comes) may result from sustained dollar depreciation (as in the 1970s), implying a capital loss for China and other major holders of US Treasuries. Alternatively, China could eventually become a new supplier of reserve assets. In this scenario, the supply of the reserve asset would align with the world’s fast-growing regions.
This connection could be direct, if the renminbi acquires reserve-currency status; or indirect, if the International Monetary Fund’s unit of account, special drawing rights, becomes a favoured asset of reserve managers, as the renminbi is now in the SDR currency basket. Reserve status for the SDR is a long-held IMF ambition, though the idea has never gotten much traction.
But there is a third possibility: global demand for US reserve assets may subside. While China’s ongoing capital flight is fueling an immediate and substantial decline in demand for US Treasuries, a more sustainable scenario would entail China’s transition to a managed floating exchange-rate regime with a deeper domestic financial market — and less emphasis on maintaining a credible war chest of foreign reserves.
Project Syndicate
The writer is Professor of the International Financial System at Harvard University’s Kennedy School of Government
source : gulfnews
GMT 12:25 2017 Tuesday ,13 June
Malaysia Needs To Identify Areas Of Specialisation To Remain Competitive Globally - PM NajibGMT 19:57 2017 Friday ,26 May
US economy posts tepid 1.2% growthGMT 05:37 2017 Monday ,13 March
Manila eyes ‘golden age of infrastructure’GMT 06:37 2017 Thursday ,09 March
Brazil’s economy dips 3.6% in 2016GMT 19:48 2017 Monday ,06 March
Greek PM upbeat about Greece's return to growth despite negative economic figuresMaintained and developed by Arabs Today Group SAL.
All rights reserved to Arab Today Media Group 2021 ©
Maintained and developed by Arabs Today Group SAL.
All rights reserved to Arab Today Media Group 2021 ©
Send your comments
Your comment as a visitor